Site icon Narrow Road Capital

Second Round Submission to the Financial System Inquiry

Introduction

Narrow Road Capital is pleased to be able to make a second round submission to the Financial System Inquiry (the Inquiry). Narrow Road Capital is an Australian fund manager specialising in high yield and distressed Australian credit. It is therefore well placed to make a submission on issues relating to credit and lending activities. This submission goes beyond the limited interests of Narrow Road Capital as a small business providing investment advice, focussing instead on what is best for ordinary consumers, taxpayers and the Australian economy as a whole.

This submission has responded to selected areas with summarised answers. There is much more that can be added to the discussion on these issues, but this is best done in a face to face setting where questions and views can be fed back and forth. In evaluating the second round submissions the Inquiry should consider organising group discussions that bring together opposing views, moderated by the Inquiry committee members. Such discussions could yield new solutions and consensus outcomes, or at least clarify the opposing views for the Inquiry members to make judgement on. Narrow Road Capital is willing to participate in any form of feedback that the Inquiry committee would like to use and encourages the Inquiry to consult widely in the second round.

The primary issue covered in this submission is bank capital levels and supervision. The financial crisis showed the enormous impact that poor quality lending by banks can have on an economy in two main ways. Firstly, poor quality lending by banks can have a catastrophic impact by causing bank failures resulting in costly government bailouts. Secondly, poor quality lending amplifies the boom and bust of business cycles when credit is initially easily available then subsequently becomes highly restricted. Australia had a much shallower downturn in the financial crisis relative to many other developed nations as it did not have as much poor quality lending in the years preceding the crisis. However, the experience of the early 1990’s and the losses incurred by BankWest, BoQ, BOSI, RBS and Suncorp in recent years serve as a warning that banks in Australia can make the same errors as their international peers. There is no room for complacency when dealing with the highly leveraged business model that banks operate with.

This submission also touches on:

Two additional topics on taxation and government policy have been included that are not strictly part of the requested areas of response. The tax incentives and disincentives legislated by state and federal governments have a major impact on investment allocations and are the elephant in the room for many investment issues. Without addressing these areas Australia will continue to have:

  1. overpriced housing;
  2. underinvestment in safer assets (debt securities) relative to riskier assets (property and equity); and
  3. a banking system with an unnecessary and excessive dependence on international funding.

Why do Banks Fail?

In the vast majority of historical cases, bank failure (i.e. a solvency issue not a liquidity issue) occurs from losses on poor quality lending that exceed the capital reserves available. A far less common reason for historical bank failure is losses incurred as a result of rogue trading that exceed the capital reserves available. The keys to stopping future bank failures are maintaining reasonable lending standards and higher capital levels.

Losses on bad loans have historically been concentrated in the corporate, institutional and investment banking departments. For example, subprime residential lending in the US caused major losses for many global banks. However, it was the investment banking departments where the warehousing and lending to tranches of subprime securities attracted most losses not the retail banks.

The first line of defence against lending losses is the risk culture and risk personnel of banks, as set down by the board and senior management. The second line of defence against bank failure is capital reserves held and this topic is addressed in the Bank Capital Requirements – Minimising the Risk of Failure section. The use of macroprudential tools as an overlay to a bank’s own risk policies is considered in the Macroprudential Tools sections.

All too often, risk personnel are considered second class citizens relative to relationship managers, with this often enforced by a profit centre (relationship managers) having actual or perceived authority over a cost centre (risk managers). APRA has a substantial role in overseeing that risk personnel are adequately empowered to reject excessively risky lending activities.

Recommendations

 

Bank Capital Requirements – Minimising the Risk of Failure

Banks that hold more capital, all things being equal, are less likely to require a taxpayer bailout or to default on their obligations to senior creditors. Forcing banks to hold more capital will come at a cost to someone, which could be (i) a 1-2% lower return on equity for bank shareholders, (ii) a 0.05-0.15% per annum higher interest rate for borrowers, or (iii) a blend of both of the aforementioned costs.

As the examples of Japan, Iceland & Ireland have demonstrated, the cost of bank failures on society is enormous and may take decades to be worked through. Bailout costs are rarely fully recovered. The cost of minimising this risk via higher levels of bank capital is comparatively small and is a cost that would be borne by those who benefit from the system the most, bank shareholders and/or borrowers.

Banks operating in Australia should therefore be required to hold more capital. This can be achieved at very low cost by increasing the amount of subordinated debt and preference shares issued, rather than insisting that more ordinary equity is raised. Since the introduction of Basel III conversion to equity terms, subordinated debt and preference shares are a strong form of loss absorption. In the event the solvency of a bank is in question, APRA can force exchange of the subordinated securities into equity or block the securities from being redeemed until solvency issues are rectified.

Recommendations

Banks should be required to satisfy three minimum capital levels:

The table below compares the current average capital level of the four major banks (capital type/total assets) with the proposed capital levels. A buffer relative to the recommended minimum capital levels is included to reflect that prudent banks hold more than the minimum capital levels prescribed by regulators. It shows an increase of 0.082% or 8.2 basis points on the average cost of capital for the four major banks.

Capital TypeCurrent Market Cost of CapitalAverage Major Bank Capital LevelWeighted Average Cost of CapitalAlternative Capital LevelWeighted Average Cost of Capital
Senior2.90%94.44%2.739%91.60%2.656%
Subordinated4.65%0.67%0.031%2.10%0.103%
Preference6.15%0.83%0.051%2.10%0.129%
Equity11.00%4.06%0.447%4.20%0.462%
TotalN/A100.00%3.268%100.00%3.350%

Given the explicit guarantee of retail deposits and the implicit guarantee of other senior creditors, the federal government is entitled to insist that the risk of failure is minimised and capital levels are increased. The substantial funding gap that makes Australian banks reliant upon overseas funding is another systemic risk that demands Australia have higher capital levels than its international peers. Elevated house prices also pose a risk to the Australian banking system and an increase in the countercyclical capital buffers should be considered.

These proposed ratios will not make any bank bulletproof but will substantially lower the risk of a bank failing with minimal impact on the cost or availability of credit.

Bank Capital Requirements – Residential Lending

The ability of the four major banks to use the Basel III rules to lower their RWA, in addition to their lower funding costs has resulted in an uneven playing field relative to smaller banks and non-banks. The Basel III rules wrongly imply that residential lending of major banks is less risky than other lenders.

The Basel III system for calculating the RWA of residential lending has resulted in some of four major Australian banks holding less than 1.60% total capital against residential loans. As there has not been a substantial downturn in residential property for over 20 years the data relied upon to create for the calculations that underpin this is highly likely to underestimate the future risk of losses.

Recommendations

An alternative three tier system is proposed for the weighting of residential lending relative to the standard RWA:

Applying these minimums to all ADI lenders will partly correct the capital weighting imbalances that the four major banks benefit from, but will not change the cost of funding differential with non-major bank lenders. The Government Support for RMBS section addresses one way to close this cost of funding gap.

Macroprudential Tools

Macroprudential tools are an essential part of the tool kit for an effective bank regulator. The blunt instrument of central bank overnight rates cannot be expected to deliver ideal rates of inflation, unemployment, GDP growth and credit risk taking all at the same time. Macroprudential tools fill part of this gap, and they are particularly useful in economic environments where low base rates are leading to excessive risk taking. In conjunction with counter cyclical capital buffers, macroprudential tools can serve as a brake on excessive credit risk and/or credit growth.

Recommendations

The SNC program allows the OCC to review and grade the risk of the loans and set minimum capital holdings for each loan. One outcome of this process in the last twelve months has been that the OCC is setting maximum leverage for loans at six times EBITDA, effectively banning banks from holding loans rated (or of the equivalent risk to) B- or lower. These loans are therefore shifted away from the highly leveraged balance sheets of banks to better capitalised shadow banking lenders such as fund managers and CLOs.

SNC type reviews will also provide APRA with far greater insights on the quality of lending in the institutional and investment banking departments and allow for more accurate setting of countercyclical capital buffers. Initially, APRA is unlikely to have the staff with the required skill set to conduct all aspects of such a program. APRA should consider partnering with private sector credit analysts such as rating agencies or fund managers when assessing the credit risk of individual transactions.

Dealing with Bank Failures

It is almost inevitable that a bank failure will occur in Australia at some point in the future. A single, small failure does not necessarily indicate a breakdown in prudential oversight or pose systemic risk. It is most important that the process for dealing with a failing bank is known in advance by senior creditors, subordinated creditors/shareholders, APRA and the federal government. The question of bailing in senior creditors/implicit guarantees is unresolved.

APRA should take note of the US case where a hedge fund is suing the federal government over the way the conservatorship of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac has been dealt with. Litigation is also being foreshadowed for the Banco Espirito Santo restructure. These cases serve as a warning on what can happen when policy is developed on the run and markets are left trading on uncertain regulatory and government outcomes. The current period of relative stability in Australia is an opportune time to warn all parties in advance of the process that will apply for an ADI that exhibits solvency issues.

Recommendations

The process for dealing with an ADI that exhibits solvency issues should be:

Government Support for RMBS

The provision of support for RMBS via government purchases or guarantees is one of a number of ways to deal with the concentration of residential lending within the four major banks. However, if not structured, implemented and managed correctly government support for RMBS comes with the risk of taxpayers being left with substantial losses as was the case with Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.

Correcting the imbalance in capital required to be held against residential mortgages (addressed earlier in Bank Capital Requirements – Residential Lending) will to some extent level the playing field for smaller lenders. However, it will not address the advantage the four major banks enjoy in funding costs. This competitive imbalance should be the primary reason for consideration of government support of RMBS and thus the four major banks should not have access to such assistance.

Recommendations

There are two potential ways for government support to be provided: on balance sheet funding or via a guarantee of debt. From the experience of the two government programs mentioned on balance sheet funding is likely to be the most efficient form of funding. In this model the federal government would issue additional Commonwealth bonds and use the proceeds to fund the purchase of AAA rated RMBS.

At current rates there would be a gap of approximately 1% between federal government cost of funds and the interest rates paid on AAA rated RMBS. If the federal government was to charge a rate of bank bills + 0.50% it could receive approximately 0.65% net interest margin but still provide a substantial 0.35% discount to issuers and thus equalise the cost of funding issue.

The experience with the federal government guarantee of senior bank funding was that it did lower the cost of long term funding to below where banks otherwise would have raised debt, but only for a short period. The market did not treat the insured debt as being equivalent risk to Commonwealth bonds (in terms of margins that the debt traded at) with a perception existing that the federal government could withdraw or not honour the guarantee at some later point.

Whilst a federal government guarantee would provide some benefit to issuers in lowering their cost of funding, the inefficiency of the design means that either the government would receive a lower risk premium for the same risk or that issuers would receive less of a discount on their funding costs. It would seem sensible that if the federal government was to choose to provide assistance it should provide on balance sheet funding and thus receive the highest return for the risk taken.

If such a program is to be established it should come with a maximum capacity that can make a meaningful difference to the competitive landscape but not so much that the federal government dominates the funding of the residential property lending. An initial limit of $50 billion deployed at a maximum rate of $2 billion of purchases per month could be a good balance of not too little or too much at 7.3% of the $27 billion average of new residential loan commitments each month. A review of the effectiveness of the program at $20 billion and $40 billion of purchased securities would be appropriate.

Given the size of the program and risk issues involved the federal government should look to outsource the credit assessment responsibilities to the private sector. For a mandate of such a substantial size, a cost of well under 0.01% per annum should be expected in a publicly run tender process.

Availability of Credit for Small Businesses

Complaints about the lack of credit available for small businesses are almost always made by people who have a fundamental misunderstanding of the different roles of debt and equity in a capital structure. As debt has upside limited to the interest rate charged but the potential for 100% downside in the event of a company failure it is only suited to situations where (i) there is a very high likelihood of full repayment or (ii) if non-payment occurs then there is a high likelihood of losses being small.

The failure rate for small businesses varies between studies and time periods, but as a guide at least one-third of companies cease operating during their first five years. Most small businesses have no material hard assets which can be sold to repay creditors in the event of insolvency. As a result, few small businesses will be a good risk for a lender without additional security, such as the property of the owner, being offered to support the loan.

Given this high risk profile, the funding needs of most small businesses (and particularly those with no track record) are better matched with equity. This will most often be supplied from the savings of the founder/s, with angel investors and venture capital other avenues for equity financing. With an increasing number of non-bank lenders making debt finance available as well as the development of peer to peer funding platforms, small businesses have sufficient options available for debt financing providing they have a sufficiently low risk business proposition.

Recommendations

Insolvency and External Administration

Any discussion of insolvency reform must begin with the understanding that creditors of a company are the priority in insolvency and their right to be paid for goods or services provided is paramount. Ordinary creditors (employees, trade creditors and the ATO) cannot be expected to assess and monitor the risk of not being paid. Rather, they should be able to function with an understanding that their supply of goods and services is to a solvent entity that will pay the amount due within the time period agreed.

Company directors, senior management and financiers are in a position to assess risk and to take action if risk levels are excessive. In almost all cases of company insolvency, directors and senior management have ignored warning signs and have failed to raise equity or sell assets to strengthen the financial position of the company in the months and years prior to insolvency.

Companies that take excessive risk and fail to pay for goods or services received have effectively stolen from their creditors. The have engaged in a (typically undisclosed) “heads I win, tails you lose” gamble with their creditors capital. Company directors and senior management that preside over such failures should be responsible for losses incurred by ordinary creditors unless it can be proven that the situation was completely unforeseeable and that they have acted in a prudent fashion at all times.

Recommendations

As well as cost issues, the US system allows for management that often caused the financial issues to remain in control of the company and to fight against senior creditors for the benefit of shareholders. The current Australian system already allows for major creditors to work together and to grant a deferral of obligations, with standstills regularly given by banks to struggling borrowers. If a company cannot convince its creditors to forestall action it has no reason to continue to trade and to risk inflicting greater losses on its creditors.

There are many benefits to the proposed restricted accounts system including:

MySuper & Superannuation Fees

The introduction of MySuper encourages superannuation funds to offer two different strategies. The MySuper option should be the low fee and primarily passive management strategy with few or no additional features such as life, disability and income protection insurance. Non-MySuper strategies could include higher fee asset allocations, such as private equity, hedge funds and traditional active management funds as well as insurance options.

Despite the substantial growth of funds in superannuation in the last decade overall fee levels have barely declined. It seems that the lack of explicit restrictions on fee levels has been to detriment of members with most superannuation funds and the fund managers they use having made limited progress in reducing costs.

Recommendations

Whilst the preference is typically to leave the market to resolve fee levels, the failure to meaningfully reduce fees and the cost of this failure on retirement incomes justifies intervention. MySuper products must be true to label and actually have very low fees. The recommended cap for non-MySuper products allows superannuation managers to choose active management strategies but requires that the underlying managers must perform well to be paid well.

Superannuation Contribution Caps

The primary purpose of superannuation is to increase the income of retirees thus reducing the demand on the federal government for age based pensions. It therefore makes sense to encourage all working age Australians to target a specific retirement balance that will be sufficient to fund a decent lifestyle for at least 20 years.

Recommendations

The taxation of superannuation should align with the target retirement balance, with a two tier system proposed. When contributors have less than the target balance a lower rate (for instance 15%) should apply to all contributions and income earned within the fund. Once the target balance is exceeded, then a higher rate of taxation (for instance 30%) should apply to contributions and income. By applying a higher taxation rate once the target balance is reached, the need for caps on annual contributions can be removed. The perceived tax subsidy for superannuation largely disappears when the higher taxation rate is applied to larger balances.

Portability of Superannuation

Superannuation is money put aside for retirement and as such it does not require daily or weekly liquidity. Imposing very short switching periods can encourage excessive switching which will increase the fees charged and decrease the overall return for members. Short switching periods also discourage long term investments, with more volatile but liquid assets (such as equities) required to match potential redemptions when less volatile direct holdings may be more optimal.

Recommendations

Financial Advice for the Majority of Australians

The debate over the provision of financial planning and advice is primarily focussed on advice for the wealthiest members of society. Given their larger balances of investable assets (i.e. excluding the primary residence), there is a much higher level of competition and quality of service available as wealth increases.

The majority of the population has less than $200,000 of investable assets and therefore fees for service can quickly amount to more than 1% per annum. For many Australians basic financial advice is either not available at a reasonable cost or will be provided by groups with a vested interest such as staff at a bank branch or an adviser employed by their superannuation fund.

Recommendations

Financial Planning and Management – Disclosure of Conflicts of Interest and Use of Titles

Recommendations

This could be a simple as “I am a salesperson not a financial advisor which means that I may earn commissions by selling products and services to you. The products and services I am selling may not be in your best interest and you may want to seek independent financial advice before agreeing to purchase.”

Funding of ASIC/APRA

One of the lessons ASIC and APRA should learn from their US counterparts is that fines are an effective way of discouraging bad behaviour. A secondary outcome is that regulators who are issuing fines and agreeing large financial settlements are using their powers to see that those behaving badly are paying a disproportionate share of the total cost of regulatory oversight.

ASIC particularly has been weak in issuing fines and sanctions to the point where it is often called the “corporate watch puppy”. Despite evidence of fraud and forgery at the financial planning departments of Macquarie Bank and the Commonwealth Bank there appears to have been no fines issued or criminal charges laid.

Recommendations

The various US regulators are now commonly agreeing settlements in the billions of dollars with banks for conduct that is arguably no worse than occurred at Macquarie Bank and the Commonwealth Bank. In similar US cases, senior management are being forced to leave with bonuses paid in previous years being clawed back.

Fines of such large scale also enhance shareholder engagement as they cannot be considered a cost of doing business. Fines that reduce an annual profit by more than 10% are a significant motivator for shareholders to hold their boards and senior management accountable for misconduct under their watch. ASIC appears to have forgotten it has the power to approve and revoke licences (which are essential for conducting business in the financial services sector) and therefore has no excuse for not severely punishing misconduct.

Credit Charge Surcharging

The current system has clearly not worked with airlines and the taxi industry flagrantly charging well beyond a cost recovery level for credit cards.

Recommendations

Key Reasons for Excessive House Prices

Australia regularly ranks at or near the bottom of indices of housing affordability. There are many factors that feed into this, with low interest rates and easy access to credit part of the issue. However, many other countries also have these factors without similar affordability issues. Overshadowing the private sector variables (cost and availability of credit) are the policies of the federal and state governments that have far more long term impact on house prices. Analysis focussing on demand, supply and incentive factors highlights government created distortions.

On the demand side, Australia continues to have relatively high population growth for a developed country due to both very strong net migration and natural increase. Whilst not entirely comparable given their higher population density, Hong Kong and Singapore are other examples of high population growth and low levels of housing affordability being interlinked.

On the supply side, government policy often restricts the release of land for housing or increases to the density of existing housing land, substantially increasing the cost of development. The supply of labour in the construction industry is also restricted which increases the cost of building.

The financial incentives offered by governments for owning housing include first home buyer grants, negative gearing allowances and capital gains tax reductions. Unlike many other developed countries Australia does not have the financial disincentive of land tax (a highly progressive form of tax) using stamp duty and developer levies instead. These opaque transaction costs are often forgotten or disregarded when investment decisions are made.

Without correcting these imbalances with a major overhaul of the taxation system, government schemes will have little or no positive impact on affordability. Contrary to the aim, first home buyer grants have made housing more unaffordable and allowing potential buyers to withdraw superannuation to purchase a home would do the same.

Development of Debt Investments – Taxation Issues

Simplifying disclosure requirements and making more debt instruments available via the ASX will somewhat help to increase the proportion of debt investments held by Australians. However, the primary reason for Australia having a low level of debt investment relative to other countries is that our taxation system rewards investment in equity and property and penalises investment in debt products.

Equities and property benefit from capital gains tax reductions, negative gearing allowances and the rebate of company tax via franking credits. Debt investments receive no such assistance with interest received taxed at the full marginal income tax rate. These taxation policies have the effect of rewarding investors for making riskier investments and penalising them for making safer investments. The obvious outcomes are that Australia has relatively high house prices, is over-allocated to listed equities and the direct ownership equivalents (i.e. commercial property, infrastructure and private equity) and has banks that are reliant on international funding.

The penalising of debt investments is particularly harsh in a low interest rate environment.  Investors on the top marginal tax rate currently receive negative real returns on even the best term deposit rates available. Whilst the Inquiry has said it is not looking at taxation issues, the elephant in the room for many of Australia’s biggest financial issues should not go unmentioned in the final report.

End of Submission

Exit mobile version